Page 10 - ENGLISH_Housing
P. 10

Note    :  Latest available data are presented. The figures in parentheses represent
                      the year to which the data pertain.

               Sources:    Official Statistics of Japan, Statistics and Census Service Macau,
                      Department of Statistics Singapore, Kim (2014), Statistics Sweden, GOV.UK,
                      and National Low Income Housing Coalition.




              2.2 The Problem with Proper ty

              Ownership


                     As Table 1 and 2 show, Hong Kong has a massive public sector
              housing programme on a scale that is unprecedented in free-market
              economies. It is undeniable that the government of Hong Kong is the single
              largest landlord, developer, and operator of housing within the territory.
              While Hong Kong is often compared with Singapore in terms of housing
              policy, the two housing programmes are critically different because of their
              different policies on homeownership and tenancy rights.

                     Singapore has allowed for the establishment of an active market
              in public sector housing for rental, as well as for sales and purchases. The
              units are rented and sold to eligible households at subsidised prices. After
              five years from the date of effective purchase, owned units can be sold on
              the open market to eligible permanent residents of Singapore. In addition,
              the owner of the units can even sublet the unit, in whole or in part, on
              the open market. As a consequence, there has been no impediment to
 Table 1. Domestic households by type of housing, 2015
              the emergence of a market for public sector housing both for renters and
              owners.


                     In Hong Kong however, restrictions have rendered the market
              for such units effectively non-existent and non-functional, with grave
              socioeconomic consequences far beyond housing issues. This is because
              unlike Singapore, the so-called “subsidised” sales flats in Hong Kong is not,
              in fact, subsidised. The prevailing mechanism of subsidised sales flats is as
 (*) Subsidised sales flats that can be traded in open market are excluded.
     Census and Statistics Department.  follows:
               (i)  Assume a subsidised sales unit has an estimated market value of $1
                  million (HK$, same hereafter unless otherwise specified). It is first sold
                  at a “discount” of, say, 30% against the market value (i.e. $700,000) to an
                  eligible household satisfying the relevant means test;

               (ii)  The government also acts as the guarantor for the said property,
                  allowing the household to obtain a mortgage up to 95% of the
                  discounted price (i.e. $665,000);

               (iii)  The unpaid 30% of the house’s market value (i.e. $300,000), is
                  commonly termed the “unpaid (land) premium”, and is payable to the
                  government when the unit is sold in the open market in the future
                  upon satisfying other requirements; and

              (iv)  The value of this unpaid premium is determined with reference to the
                  market value not at the date of occupation of unit, but at the time
                  when repayment is to be made. For example, if home prices double
                                                                                                                  15
   5   6   7   8   9   10   11   12   13   14   15